By
Gordon Elley on
Thursday, April 13, 2000 - 07:11 pm:
I am looking for a good example
of a "Shared Savings Clause" to insert Via SPI block Mod or
single mod depending on the circumstance. On the Apache Long Bow
the shared savings clause used in conjunction with a
"Obsolescence/Technology clause has incentiveized both the
Program Office and the contractor to work toward a common goal
of more product for the dollar. The Army AR office has indorsed
this approach. I would like to take this approach with our Navy
and Airforce contracts.
Thanks. Gordon Elley, Acquisition Reform
Director, Air Combat Systems Northrop Grumman Corporation, El
Segundo CA
By
Ramon on Tuesday, January 25, 2000 - 08:30 am:
I've just cited a web reference
with some possible interest to this discussion under
"Industry-Government Partnering." It is fairly long, but has
added value in giving some active points of contact.
By
Vern Edwards
on Monday, January 24, 2000 - 07:59 pm:
Here's what I would do: I would
ask the contractor to propose two ways: FFP and FPIF. I'd ask
him to explain his cost reasoning for each proposal. I'd analyze
the deals then see what I could get him to sign up to at the
table. I'd use FPIF as a compromise if I couldn't get the
firm-fixed-price I wanted. But I'd go for FFP first.
The key to choosing between FFP and FPIF is whether you and your
contractor can reach an agreement on a firm-fixed-price. If you
can, then production costs are the contractor's problem and you
don't have to worry about them anymore. If you can't, then maybe
you can agree on a cost range and then develop a cost sharing
arrangement.
If you can't agree on a single number, then perhaps you can
agree on a range between the best case cost and the worst case
cost. If so, then you can negotiate profit numbers for each end
of the range. Based on those numbers you can calculate a share
ratio. All you have to do then is agree on a spot on the cost
range for your target cost.
This is a negotiation problem, not an acquisition planning
problem. Think of FPIF as a negotiation solution if you can't
agree on a firm-fixed-price. Don't think of it as an incentive;
think of it as a compromise.
I don't know much about your item. It sounds like an active
sensor (or set of sensors) hooked up to a data processing box
and a human interface. Perhaps it's a newer version of an older
system. Perhaps the system is a new thing, but the pieces are
based on older designs. You may have enough cost data to reach
agreement on a reasonable unit price.
Have fun with this. I used to do these sole source negotiations
all the time. They were great fun. A lot more fun than source
selections.
I envy you.
By
Brian Fisher
on Monday, January 24, 2000 - 07:26 pm:
First, don't expect significant
AR savings on a small-lot contract. The nonrecuring costs,
limited learning improvements, lower-tier vendor prices for
small purchase quantities, and other problems facing small-lot
contracts, will limit the potential for substantial savings.
Also, given the end-use of the technology (mine hunting), I also
would not expect any immediate spin-offs that would enable a
contractor to recoup the costs elsewhere, so expect to pay more.
That being said, have you considered fully the issues of GFP,
GFM, and any other avenue through which NAVSEA can lower the
contractor's production costs?
Also, have you reviewed the Capital Programming Guide in OMB
Circular A-11, Part 3 Supplement? This Guide provides several
potential cost-saving approaches that you might wish to consider
if you have not already done so.
Finally, have you spoken to OFPP to obtain their input? (FYI:
One of the OFPP staffers is a recent "acquisition" from NAVSEA
and might be able to push the right buttons for you.) Try (202)
395-4761. You might even try calling OMB's National Security
Division, Force Structure and Investment Branch, at (202)
395-3884, to discuss funding alternatives and approaches. Rob
Goldberg (the Branch Chief) and his staff have received many
accolades for their assistance to DoD agencies in implementing
creative approaches when funding is tight. (VERY HELPFUL).
An FFP contract MIGHT sufficiently motivate and compensate --
without the FPI mess -- a contractor for its risk of entering
into a small-lot production contract. You state that your
potential sole-source awardee "has successfully competed through
an open competition and several 'down-selects' in the
development phase." It sounds like you and the contractor have
reached a general understanding of the program's technical and
other basic requirements. If your cognizant technical staffs
have identified both the known and the known-unknown risks, and
if you can appropriately allocate those risks -- as well
establishing a process by which to allocate potential
unknown-unknown risks between the parties, then a well-written
FFP contract might allow the contractor sufficient "trade space"
within the program's general concept to produce a system that
meets your technical requirements while meeting or beating the
contractor's cost requirements.
However, additional facts may indicate that your program might
or might not have advanced to a point where the design or the
technology is mature enough to justify (at least in my overly
cautious mind) shifting essentially all of the risk to the
contractor via an FFP arrangement. I believe that if you follow
the simple steps outlined in the Capital Programming Guide, you
will have at least considered some of the more basic issues not
addressed in your posting here.
Good luck,
Brian
By
A.M. Shaw on Monday,
January 24, 2000 - 12:33 pm:
It seems as though FPIF is the
textbook answer to my question but it also seems as though no
one really thinks that's a very good solution. Does anyone have
suggestions for alternatives?
The Contractor in question has successfully competed through an
open competition and several "down-selects" in the development
phase and will be awarded a sole source contract for the 6-12
production units.
By
Ramon on Saturday, January 22, 2000 - 01:49 am:
Going from my previous general
observation to the problem at hand it seems you are in a
situation at least similar to the LRIP phase. You have a
prototype and need to work on production processes as well as
possibly knock some rough edges off the prototype with potential
minor design changes.
One of the things you want to do here is have the contractor
work on production innovation to lower cost and, if possible,
improve the product. One old lesson relearned from the auto
industry was to involve production in design modifications that
do not adversely impact performance, but enhance production. If
I recall, the Ford Taurus was once touted as such a case. Such
work can also enhance maintainability.
If I recall correctly places like DSMC have done research and
collected some metrics on LRIP scenarios. I believe GAO has also
done some negative reporting on some misuses. Anyway, some of
the data collected on LRIP and best manufacturing practices
might be a place to look.
I'm grasping at some reading years ago, but I believe there were
some metrics on expected production efficiencies for given types
of things over given numbers of units. I believe some incentives
made either follow on production or sharing arrangements
contingent on whether actual efficiency met the expected curve,
but it has been a long time since I dug into that interesting
corner. You might check with DSMC to see if they have any recent
LRIP metrics that might apply to your situation.
By
Vern Edwards
on Friday, January 21, 2000 - 08:40 pm:
Hi Larry:
No, I haven't changed my mind. I don't like the formula
incentive contracts. I don't think they work. I think it's too
hard to develop a sound incentive structure and I think they
make contract administration more complicated than it needs to
be.
But A. M. Shaw asked what kinds of incentives he/she could use,
and I gave him/her the standard line on incentive contracts.
I guess I'm getting mellow. Lately, I've just tried to answer
the question.
Vern
By
Larry Edwards
on Friday, January 21, 2000 - 06:06 pm:
Vern: On 22 Aug 98 in this
forum, you said:
“One last piece of personal
advice -- Whatever you do, don't use a fixed-price-incentive
(FPI) contract unless somebody holds a gun to your head and
demands that you do. If they point a gun at you and demand that
you use an FPI contract with successive targets, tell them to go
ahead and shoot you. “ This is one of my favorite quotes since
I share this sentiment. Have you changed your mind or did you
mean it to apply only to this 1998 instance?
By
Vern Edwards
on Friday, January 21, 2000 - 05:34 pm:
Well, it's hard to answer your
question without more information about your program, but here
are a couple of thoughts.
The ultimate incentive to control production costs would be a
competitively-awarded firm-fixed-price contract. But I don't
know if you have competition or whether you feel that the use of
an FFP contract is practicable.
If you don't have competition and you don't think you can
otherwise establish a fair and reasonable firm-fixed-price, then
a fixed-price incentive (firm) contract (FPIF) would seem to be
the most appropriate choice. DOD often uses FPIF contracts for
initial production of non-commercial items.
I wouldn't think you would need to use any type of
cost-reimbursement contract for a production requirement.
By
A.M. Shaw on Friday,
January 21, 2000 - 03:38 pm:
Vern-
What kind of contract I'm going to use is the essence of what
I'm asking for suggestions on. We have a couple of ideas and
want to see what other kinds of vehicles are out there that we
may not have thought of. This is something we're trying to
"think outside the box" on.
The item in question is a "mine hunting" system for a submarine.
The prototype is being funded and developed on a separate
contract and I think production will be continuous.
By
Ramon on Friday, January 21, 2000 - 02:19 pm:
This is somewhat an aside and in
no way intended to be sarcastic, but I do sometimes wonder about
all this talk of motivation and incentive as if it were some
sort of magic.
I do recognize incentives and motivation have a place, but I
wonder if the key is not avoiding disincentives and careful
selection of an already motivated contractor.
First, I doubt there is any way to motivate a mule to win the
Derby anymore than you'd motivate a racehorse to effectively
pack heavy loads into Grand Canyon. Motivation is best captured
in selection of the right contractor with a record of
performance. A good performer is more likely to do well even in
a new venture or without clever incentive programs.
One way to turn a performer into a laggard is to plague them
with disincentives. I'm afraid some government contracting
organizations and agencies are pretty effective in that respect.
I have to wonder if half the time were spent on really
eliminating disincentives (Most good contractors know "rotten
bait" when they see it.) and then on effective selection as on
various incentive and motivation schemes we would not do better.
By
Vern Edwards
on Friday, January 21, 2000 - 12:32 pm:
The choice of incentive depends
in large measure on the contract type. What type of contract are
you planning to use?
Also, what type of item? Is this a prototype? An item that has
been previously produced? Will production be continuous or
on-order? Is the item largely hand-produced, like a spacecraft,
or is production highly automated?
Etc.
By
A.M. Shaw on Friday,
January 21, 2000 - 12:03 pm:
Anybody have any suggestions
about how to incentivize a Contractor to keep production costs
low on a production contract which requires low production
quantities? (Throughout the life of the contract only 6-12
systems will be produced) I'm looking for examples of how
similar situations have been handled, including the application
of Acquisition Reform.
|