By Ramon Jackson
on Friday, March 3, 2000 - 09:05 pm:
Eric, I think we are talking
about two different things here. You give a list of underlying
procurement principles, but that is not what I understand this
service contract issue to be about. I don't think there is any,
or very much, argument about underlying contract principles. The
argument I've seen is about how a long term service contract is
structured to meet almost certain stresses and changes in
service demands without breaking those contracting principles.
How, for example, does on in 2000 build into a computer
maintenance service contract running into 2004 a mechanism to
meet some predictable, but undescribable technology, operational
or threat change. Write too much "wiggle room" in and you have
valid criticism that you've given the contractor way too much
rope. Write a tightly structured tasking trying to cover every
base and suddenly find you simply cannot accomodate some
situation without a huge flap because the PO and CO have made a
neat box requiring major restructuring to meet a pressing
unexpected need. I'm arguing that there are techniques and
processes for judicious identification of probable stress points
and placement of relief valves in the contract at inception that
provide flex without license. It does perhaps require a
different sort of planning.
In simplistic terms, I think they can avoid the incident I once
heard about where the housekeeping contract was drawn too
tightly to allow intensive rest room clean-up during a big
conference with many times normal load and longer hours of use.
Looked bad for the organization, but they had so tightly bound
the thing that getting extra work hours and extended time
windows was going to require a change order. Not one of your
underlying principles was violated, in fact, they may have been
over exercised.Zeal for overly precise specification and
controls apparently led to an unsightly mess.
That is one of the places POs and COs can also come into
conflict. Beautiful, tightly drawn written contract, lousy
result perhaps as a result of being too beautiful and too tight
in the abstract without ability to meet the demands of the
actual.
Ramon
By
Eric Ottinger on
Friday, March 3, 2000 - 12:17 pm:
Ramon,
I took an undergraduate course from a professor who had done
some interesting statistical analysis of Supreme Court
decisions. He had concluded that there were only a half dozen
underlying issues that would decide most cases that reach the
Supreme Court. His statistical analysis would not tell you what
the vote would be for any particular case, but it would predict
very accurately how the justices would line up.
I don’t think there are more than a half dozen principles
underlying Federal Procurement.
Arms-Length dealing.
Public Accountability.
Don’t spend any money that Congress hasn’t appropriated
Competition is Good.
Prices should be fair and supported by objective facts or data.
Etc. (Pick your own.)
If you understand those principles and organize your knowledge
around those principles, it isn’t hard for the experienced
professional to find the knowledge he/she needs and make fairly
accurate predictions about the way things will play out in any
particular scenario. It isn’t rocket science and it doesn’t
require a Philadelphia lawyer.
Folks who think otherwise want to trade on their “expertise.”
Or, they want to bluff their customers with their unique and
esoteric knowledge. Or, they have an agenda. (Personal Opinion.)
Each agency has its own set of bureaucratic hurdles and gates;
purportedly, to make sure that the worker bees don’t do anything
really stupid or embarrassing. Also, to make sure that the boss
doesn’t look stupid when his/her boss asks a question. Most of
the working knowledge that we have is knowledge of how to
operate within a specific bureaucratic environment. Much of this
is an intuitive understanding of what the real agendas are
behind the formal agendas.
(There are some very complex and specialized areas of expertise
in procurement, e.g. transportation, quality assurance, CAS,
Part 25, SBA regulations. We don’t normally have to deal with
more than one or a few of these in any particular job and we
usually have specialists to guide us.)
(Also, when things go wrong, we wander into the domain of the
Lawyers. As several have pointed out, don’t go there unless
absolutely necessary.)
(When I say, "Go see a smart lawyer," that means that, in my
opinion, we have wandered away from the Water Cooler into the
swamp.)
Getting back to the matter at hand. It is a common sense
priciple that we should know what we are buying and be able to
count, measure or evaluate it in some fashion. The principle is
simple. The implementation can be difficult when we are not
buying simple goods and services.
Eric
By Ramon Jackson on Friday,
March 3, 2000 - 10:06 am:
Eric, this touches on something
we've discussed before in connection with credentials vs.
experience. A quote from J. A. Proude, "Experience teaches
slowly, and at the cost of mistakes" applies. Some never learn
from mistakes, gaining uninformed and useless "experience." When
learning takes place we have valuable and sometimes
unquantifiable experience with deep knowledge.
That old saw about the consultant gets that across. The man with
the non operative engine who called in the expert who finally
tapped a spot with a hammer complained that he could have paid
someone $5 to do that instead of $1,000. The expert replied that
in that case the hammer tap was $5, the $995 was knowing where
to tap.
It is true that this is often not laid out in the usual
"rational" form. No drawings, papers or proposals. It is still
there. Maybe the other old saying about someone having
"forgotten" more than most know is a way of putting this. We all
have knowledge we've "forgotten" that influences decisions. It
is not necessarily irrelevant. It sometimes is vital. It is
difficult to extract and examine and is sometimes explained away
as an expert's "gut feeling," but it is not uneducated
speculation and guesswork. Inexperienced participants, who may
have nothing more than that as foundation for their opinion,
will often make such accusations. I expect we've all seen
meetings degenerate where foolish courses of action were pressed
by a clueless majority over an experienced minority on the basis
that nobody's opinion counts more than anyone else's. That has
been responsible for some of history's great disasters and
uncounted small fiascoes.
An interesting story in connection with the search for the USS
SCORPION may show a method of capturing this in better form. I
believe there is a paper about this somewhere, but I've
forgotten where so I'll have to go on memory. The experts were
swirling when someone who had studied this tapping of forgotten
and gut knowledge applied a means of extracting it. He proposed
a betting game (bottles of Scotch I believe) in which the
experts would place bets against various possibilities
influencing actual location. If I recall, some fruitful advances
were made because high bets were placed against some. None of
the experts could quite explain in detail, demonstrate with
equations, or write a paper on why -- they were tapping deep
experience they had "forgotten."
I believe one of the web site cites (Ah! There is a fun one with
that grating misuse of "site," "cite," and "sight" we've seen so
much of lately.) I gave earlier touched on tapping such expert
knowledge of a group to shed light into the shadows of bounded
rationality. Techniques exist for doing this in an organized
way. Formalized risk assessment uses some and I believe other
disciplines have developed others. For multi million dollar
contracts it would seem worth applying this to formally
delineate areas of the unexpected and shed as much light as
possible on probabilities within. Unfortunately, except perhaps
in some high tech and R&D work, this does not seem to be common.
It could prove a sound investment of effort.
Ramon
By
Eric Ottinger on
Tuesday, February 29, 2000 - 05:31 pm:
Beverly,
Good input! But.
It isn’t that I question the use of performance measures in
service contracts. I question whether there is really a
significant impact when you look at the big picture. I honestly
don’t know what proportion of the service contract dollars go
for food service contracts and such, and what proportion goes
for highly technical SETAs and such.
It is an axiom in the education field that all experiments
succeed. I am glad that you think that this is a success, but
you will need to be more specific to be convincing.
I was about to ask you how you applied performance based
principles to general scope advisory and assistance contracts;
then you said the secret word: "TASK" (which are not necessarily
FASA Task Orders).
The problem with applying merely quantitative measures to highly
professional work is that unquantifiable qualitative issues may
be much more important than the quantifiable measures.
For instance your HMO may think your doctor is whiz because he
processes each patient in less than 10 minutes.
If however, you are the patient and he misses your cancer, which
is not diagnosed until six months in the future, you may have a
very different attitude toward that doctor.
(Note, that a careful reading of the regulation indicates that
you have satisfied the “performance based” when you apply it to
the extent which is practicable, which may not be much.)
I am not opposed to quantifiable measures. (That is motherhood
and apple pie, and I am sure Vern would agree.) But, the more
difficult and more professional the work, the more the emphases
has to be on judgmental, qualitative measures of performance.
I think most of the skepticism was directed at the detailed and
comprehensive SOW which must describe in detail what the
contractor is doing today and describe what he/she will be doing
five years in the future, at the same level of detail. (As long
as we have some freedom to fill in those details using tasks,
there is hope.)
Hoping this clarifies,
Eric
By
Eric Ottinger on
Tuesday, February 29, 2000 - 05:13 pm:
Ramon,
We all think we are rational. I would advise a young person that
arguments in the form “I am more rational than you are,” are
usually not very productive.
I was thinking of an “old school” doctor who could make a very
accurate diagnosis based on a little bit of poking, smelling and
listening. Also I was thinking of businessmen who can eyeball a
project and quickly make a fairly accurate estimate of what it
will cost. Of course, this kind of intuition reflects years of
study and experience.
Infantry officers can usually say, “That is 300 meters,” or,
“That is a kilometer,” with adequate precision. If you asked how
they know, there is no answer other than practice. The brain
does a lot of things very well in the back, where we aren’t
conscious of what the brain is doing.
If we are going to distinguish rational from reasonable,
rational has to equate to logic.
I am very skeptical about the use of formal logic in practical
affairs. Usually, when a person tells you how logical he is, he
has started from some shaky assumption and proceeded through
some process of rigorous logic to an utterly crank conclusion.
The best thing that we can all do for rationality is to be very
careful in testing our assumptions.
(Otherwise, you have made some good points as usual.)
Eric
By
Vern Edwards
on Tuesday, February 29, 2000 - 12:25 pm:
Beverly:
I'm sorry that you are puzzled about my opinions about long
term, complex service contracts. My views are neither new nor
controversial outside government policy circles. I am not an
original thinker in this regard.
I have stated my reasoning and the sources of my thinking. I
have also published several articles in which I have explained
my doubts about PBC policy. If you have read what I've written
and the sources that I've mentioned and still don't understand
how I have reached my conclusions, then I don't know what else
to say and I have nothing more to add.
With regard to your personal experiences with PBC, I can only
say that I do not know the details, but that I'm glad that you
are pleased with the results that you have had.
By Beverly Shaffer on Tuesday,
February 29, 2000 - 11:51 am:
I am very surprised at the "nay-sayers"
regarding Performance Based Service Contracting! It seems
everyone can intellectualize why it won't work, but the pilot
program has proved it does. As Quality Assurance Program
Coordinator, I have actively participated in the re-writes of
numerous contracts to the Performance Based concept. This
initial re-write is generally more time-consuming than writing
the former way, because we have to re-think the approach instead
of copying the old way. However, we anticipate that the time
spent will be well worth it. The flexibility of the Performance
Based concept lends itself to all the services we have used it
for, including base operational services such as food service
and refuse SOWs; Range Operation and Maintenance SOWs;
engineering and technical services; Advisory and Assistance
Services; etc. I really am puzzled by Vern Edwards remarks
regarding the agencies not being able to specify the results
they want before contract award. Surely, they must have a
specific result or outcome that can be identified at least in a
general manner. We have a general outcome specified on contracts
for which we further define specific outcomes for tasks under
each task order awarded under that contract.
By
Ramon on Monday, February 28, 2000 - 10:59 am:
Eric, strange, one of my
dictionaries defines "rational" as: "Having reason or the
faculty of reasoning; endowed with reason; agreeable to reason;
pertaining to or acting in conformity to reason; sane;
judicious" and another has similar language. I can only conclude
your "rational" person reaching "unreasonable" results must
suffer a form of multiple personality disorder.
I will not deny that in popular culture strict application of
rationality often acquires the label of "unreasonable." That
only proves that quite often reason and fact can't overcome
desire and prejudice, i.e., "Officer, it is unreasonable to deny
me the privilege of speeding down the shoulder for an important
meeting."
I certainly do not agree that "Reasonable decisions are often
based on the weight of many years of experience and intuitive
good judgment without much supporting detail." I'd put that into
the sheer luck category. Such decisions are reached by years of
experience gained through actual practice and absorbing
experience of others (education) and being able to sift the
meaningful details from the meaningless wild cards. That detail
may not be written or even organized for that "intuitive good
judgment," but it is most certainly there. It is probably what
we really mean by "experience." Anything else is a crap shoot.
There are plenty of people with vast experience, no interest in
learning, no ability or desire to think about what happened and
who have no memory of the meaningful detail who reach
"reasonable" conclusions (in popular terms) that are disasters.
The average casino gambling addict might be an example. Their
"experienced" and "reasonable" assumption that it is "time for
their number to come up" is poppycock. Yet many, without a clue
as to real probability theory, agree with them. The same might
be said for some contracting types who, instead of quarters,
pull the lever with the same old contracting token under the
assumption that one day they will hit.
It is not abstract theory that imposing an overly detailed
tasking in the attempt to preordain the outcome of a dynamic
service environment is playing against house odds. Experience,
from case after case, are that you will encounter some situation
that crashes into the tasking detail. Systematic recognition of
the fact you don't and can't know every eventuality and
application of rational, not blind, experience to the broad
areas can allow you to begin fencing the areas you do not know
well enough to predefine. Then more experience will allow
setting some limits to the range of uncertainty (risk assessment
operates much in this way) and could begin driving tasking that
would allow mitigation as the events unfold.
This is and it isn't rocket science. They do it, but so does
every commuter or traveler setting out with unknown weather and
traffic conditions. The recognize that things happen, they know
an accident is more likely than a Martian attack, and make
rational adjustments to accommodate the probable, but precisely
unknown obsticles.
Some similar thought in forming the contract journey can lead to
similar escape valves. One example that I think was worth its
weight in gold in developmental contracts was a funded task for
ad-hoc studies to be executed upon approval and precise
definition of the COR/COTR. I heard this was strongly opposed in
some circles as a slush fund. I suppose it could be used that
way, but used properly it was the means of meeting technical
surprises by allowing immediate exploration and development of
the issues related to a technical problem, otherwise requiring a
change order, that both buys progress and rational support for
the potential change. In more than one case it allowed
development of an alternate to the immediately assumed solution
that could be done cheaper, faster and without contract
modification.
I wonder if something similar could not work into service hours
to meet unexpected situations. For example, a computer
maintenance contract that is being stressed by increased
incidence of service loss due to virus attacks. The contract
provides for funded ad-hoc additional hours and services within
the already tailored broad tasking. Additional service in
removal and recovery can be immediately turned on while metrics
are gathered on the additional levels required long term. Time
has been bought while the need for and a rational level of
additional service in the new environment is explored.
By
Vern Edwards
on Wednesday, February 23, 2000 - 12:49 pm:
Eric:
I didn't say anything about pragmatism. The term was
"bureaucratic pragmatist," which is your term. I think it's
wonderfully descriptive, and I intend to use it a lot from now
on. (I don't know what William James would have thought of it.)
In any event, I didn't intend to use it disparagingly, just
descriptively.
By
Eric Ottinger on
Wednesday, February 23, 2000 - 12:32 pm:
Vern,
Last I heard, “Pragmatism” was the philosophy of the
distinguished American philosopher and academic, William James.
I have no idea why you should consider the word a pejorative.
You are correct in saying that researchers always have
preconceptions, if only for the purpose of framing a hypothesis
to be tested. I meant that the researcher should not be burdened
with either the preconceptions of our community or the
preconceptions of our critics.
I think a lot (but not all) of the research that is done in our
field is half-baked stuff that is often crippled by the
simplistic preconceptions and hypotheses which shape the
“research.”
(i.e. Surveys which take the form—
“Do you feel more reformed than you did a year ago? Choose a
number between 1 and 5.”)
(There is a well-known story about the young sociologist who
wanted to study the Capone gang. He found that these low-life,
thug killers sat around boring each other silly telling the same
war stories over and over again. All the researcher had to do to
make a friend was to sit down next to a gangster on a barstool
and be a willing audience for the old war stories. Somebody with
that kind of chutzpah and initiative is the person I have in
mind.)
The researcher should be young because the project that I have
in mind requires a lot of stamina. Also, it is easier sometimes
for a young person to ask really dumb, obvious questions and get
honest answers.
Eric
By
Mike
Love on Wednesday, February 23, 2000 - 11:29 am:
Research is needed - given.
Little or none is now being funded - given. Whether adequate
funding will ever materialize is unknown. (I hope some lurker
out there has research funding and will call.) The Federal
Management Association is proposing a blue ribbon panel on the
optimum size and shape of the federal government. Until then,
life goes on.
To the person trying to rationally contract for services that
cannot be defined over the long term of the contract, what
alternatives does the system provide?
· Performance based contracting with fixed pricing preferred.
· Service contracts describing what should be done.
· Cost reimbursement, level of effort.
· Time and materials from the GSA Schedule or other vehicle.
· IDIQ with each increment of work defined in the task order.
(If the TO does not describe the work, it is effectively a level
of effort or T&M contract.)
· Employment contracts.
Assuming that this person does not just want to label a contract
"performance based" and then implement it as circumstances
dictate, are the existing criteria adequate to choose between
the above? IMHO the answer is no. Can criteria be identified
that would guide the choice better based on what we know today?
My guess is yes and the criteria might already have been
identified in some of the works discussed already. But what
changes if any are necessary to allow better service contracting
in the federal government? I suspect that policy, both
contracting and personnel, needs substantial revision, both
acquisition and program managers will need training and
stakeholders must buy in.
By
Vern Edwards
on Tuesday, February 22, 2000 - 08:39 pm:
Eric:
You ask: "What I would like to know is-- Why do we, as a tribe,
stick to a theory that is so frequently contradicted by our
experience."
Answer: Because the members of the tribe think of themselves as
"bureaucratic pragmatists," or because they haven't thought
about their experience and won't read books by academics.
When the Government first promulgated the PBSC policy that now
appears in FAR Part 37, a very high level policy official called
me at home and asked me not to be too critical of the new rules
in my GWU classes and in my writings. This person said that
she/he was familiar with the writings of Macneil, Macauley,
Williamson and others, and understood them, but that those ideas
were too complicated for the working level people to understand,
much less take into account in their contracting practices.
She/he felt that the new PBSC policy was better than nothing,
and in any event it was needed to demonstrate the
adminstration's commitment to acquisition reform. See, Eric,
bureaucratic pragmatism. Oh, well, everyone to his own taste.
To the extent that people go along with questionable new
policies without question, it is either because they don't know
any better (maybe they haven't read Simon and Macneil, or maybe
they disdain academics) or because they're too busy being
reasonable to be rational. Or maybe they're just too bored or
tired to care.
P.S. There is no such thing as a researcher with no
preconceptions. Researchers do research to find out whether
their preconceptions -- read, hypotheses -- are valid or not.
P.P.S. Why does the researcher have to be young?
By
Eric Ottinger on
Tuesday, February 22, 2000 - 05:16 pm:
Chacun a son gout, Vern.
I don’t disagree. I believe I made the same argument in an
earlier thread. I mentioned a considerable amount of “private
side commentary” to that effect.
At that time, I had specifically in mind a popular book of
advice to businessmen and a casual conversation with a lawyer
acquaintance.
If “bounded rationality” will get some of our thinkers off the
dime, more power to it.
The low rent formulation is “Stuff Happens.”
What I would like to know is-- Why do we, as a tribe, stick to a
theory that is so frequently contradicted by our experience.
Regarding academia, I think it would be a very good thing if
some young researcher, with no preconceptions, would take a look
at our service contracts. I think he/she would find a lot of
interesting disconnects between theory and on-the-ground
reality.
If most 1102s were inclined to speculative thought, this chat
room would be so busy that you and I would have a hard time
getting a word in edgewise. Most of our colleagues seem to be
bureaucratic pragmatists; I try to frame my arguments
accordingly.
If I say, “It is difficult to do weather forecasts for the
Washington DC area; most of the time, when we have a foot of
snow the forecasters are caught by surprise,” there is general
agreement. If I start talking about the “butterfly effect” and
“chaos theory,” eyes glaze over and my colleagues start edging
away.
I think “bounded rationality” is relevant to our service
contracts in the same way that the “butterfly effect” is
relevant to weather forecasting. It is an interesting topic for
a bull session. For most of my colleagues it is sufficient to
know that the weather is unpredictable.
Ramon,
There is a distinction to be made between “rational” and
“reasonable.” Rational people frequently reach unreasonable
results because they don’t check their assumptions against
reality.
Reasonable decisions are often based on the weight of many years
of experience and intuitive good judgment without much
supporting detail.
(I think Bertrand Russell always made a point of demonstrating
to his wives that he was more rational than they were. He went
through a lot of wives that way. I try not to make that kind of
mistake.)
If we are going to be purveyors of sound business judgement in
this new acquisition reformed era, we need to think more like
practical businessmen and less like theorists.
Anyway, you are right. I don’t really disagree. The perfect and
perfectly detailed SOW is frequently a chimera.
I think we will have more luck persuading our colleagues if we
put more emphasis on concrete experience and less emphasis on
abstract theory. But this is just my person opinion. If the
academic approach works, that’s fine with me.
Eric
By
Vern Edwards
on Tuesday, February 22, 2000 - 02:53 pm:
Mike:
On February 22, you wrote:
"On the substance of this thread, given our current state of
knowledge is the policy mandating performance based contracting
appropriate? My reading of the discussion so far is no. The need
to define and redefine the work as it progresses will often
practically preclude even defining desired end states. Am I
correct?"
You correctly understand my view. PBC is based on the idea that
agencies can fully specify the results they want ex ante, i.e.,
before contract award. While this may be possible for simple
(one or two task), short-term service requirements, it is
difficult if not impossible for complex (multi-function),
long-term requirements.
As O.E. Williamson put it, "Comprehensive contracting is not a
realistic organizational alternative when provision for bounded
rationality is made."
Contracts for complex, long-term requirements must allow the
parties to define requirements on an ad hoc basis, as they
emerge, without having to resort to the often cumbersome and
time-consuming change order/supplemental agreement process.
Vern
By
Ramon on Tuesday, February 22, 2000 - 09:37 am:
The necessity to take rational
action when all the facts cannot be assembled and subjected to
methodical analysis for fully rational action is at least part
of what bounded rationality seems to be about. Particularly in
the human relations field the necessary raw material may simply
not exist as it might in engineering. However, this should not
be an excuse for random jumping to conclusions and rushing into
thoughtless action simply because it seems to advance toward
some assumed goal.
There are ways to assess those ill defined areas without being
driven by baseless assumptions. I suspect, from experience, we
too often take a vote rather than do an assessment.
I doubt the comment about academics reflects Eric's basic views
and to some extent it has some basis in the publish or perish
world. Unfortunately, it can be a view held widely enough to
shout down well thought out and documented observations. Good
research and facts too often get submerged in "I (or we) want
this."
By
Mike
Love on Tuesday, February 22, 2000 - 08:06 am:
Let me chime in. Rigor of
analysis and in gathering and examining facts is always welcome.
It could even be equated with being professional.
But it is often necessary and even more often advisable to take
action before a complete analysis is done. At least one
attribute of a good business or other leader is to be able to
act with some wisdom on incomplete information.
In the public acquisition field we will often be faced with
issues that need resolution, or at least action, before the
analysis is complete. No one would dispute that. Likewise no one
should dispute that one should take advantage of existing
scholarly analysis when it exists. Thus in practice, I would
hope that those who tend to favor either scholarly approaches or
going off half cocked would appreciate it when someone reminds
them with some humor (even if it is less funny than one would
hope) that there is another view.
On the substance of this thread, given our current state of
knowledge is the policy mandating performance based contracting
appropriate? My reading of the discussion so far is no. The need
to define and redefine the work as it progresses will often
practically preclude even defining desired end states. Am I
correct?
Mike
By
Ramon on Sunday, February 20, 2000 - 11:34 am:
I'm suspect Eric meant no harm
in his observation and sometimes it does seem the less clever
researchers pick safe and well plowed fields, but there seems
too much easy dismissal of real study and research into such
things as contracting. It is so "commonsense" that only
training, not study is seen as needed by many.
A quote attributed to one Henry Shaw seems to apply: "The
trouble with people is not that they don't know but that they
know so much that ain't so." That applies to all of us at
various times, but it can apply too long to whole communities.
One of my pet examples was the formal design review that was
probably formalized as a logical working mechanism for monster
programs and then became an article of faith. It was common
knowledge among some that gathering a hundred or so people in
dark suits to view slides and hear presentations was absolutely
necessary for milestone decisions. Then a study identified the
near religious ceremonial gathering as being well up on the
ladder of wasteful practices. Still, many "knew" it had to be.
When we tried to change with a more practical and realistic
review down in the plant in jeans looking at actual work it was
heresy. Presentation of the study result, official that it was,
was discounted as being theory. Powerful groups outside the
program management "knew" the full dress ceremony was absolutely
necessary. Unfortunately, facts rarely change views held as
sacred.
We need more of what Vern mentions. Not less. Then we need some
accountability to make sure it is recognized in practice.
By
Vern Edwards
on Saturday, February 19, 2000 - 08:23 pm:
I'm sure that it's fun to
ridicule sociologists studying what seems obvious to the common
man or woman, but academics and independent scholars do good
service when they confirm or disprove intuitions, commonsense
notions, and popular beliefs. First, they make the experiences
of a few accessible to all by reporting what others have
observed and by explaining its relevance and significance to
those in diverse fields of endeavour. Second, by studying and
thinking about phenomena in systematic ways, classifying those
phenomena, giving them names like "bounded rationality," and
publishing their findings, they organize and disseminate
knowledge and open the door to further study that deepens our
understanding and increases our ability to put what we know to
effective use.
By
Ramon on Friday, February 18, 2000 - 10:51 am:
"Robbed of the ability to
communicate once action was joined, they sought to overcome the
obstacles and accidents that would inevitably arise in the
unfolding of battle by ever more elaborate anticipation and
predisposition. Plans were drawn which laid down
minute-by-minute manoeuvre by the infantry and almost
yard-by-yard concentration of artillery fire, in an attempt not
so much to determine as to predestine the outcome. The attempt
was, of course, vain." [John Keegan, "The First World War"]
Where that "article of faith" Eric mentions is in force we have
the equivalent of military "experts" who never heard of von
Clausewitz and the "fog of war." They send their troops into a
meat grinder and stalemate. At least in contracting it is just
ulcers and frustration.
The First World War generals were in an iron technology bind
where the weapons were available to force stalemate and horrible
casualties, but not for breaking the lock. I don't think law and
FAR put contract people in quite such an iron box. Unwillingness
to think things through and put in the work too often results in
a fall back to "you can't do that" without exploration of a
solution within the legal framework.
Immediate recognition of the fog of contractual execution at the
inception stage can lead to much more rational approaches of
risk assessment and mitigation, concentration on doing well
those things that can be nailed down and building in
accommodating mechanisms for those that cannot. Perhaps among
the most is communication. It does expand the opportunity for
uncoordinated and even illegal contract modifications, but
systematic and controlled use within contractual structures is
vital. Non-recognition of the need to create mechanisms to
rapidly communicate, assess the dynamic conditions and make
course corrections in a contract seem to me to lead to a
similar, if less fatal, stalemate and carnage.
The things we've been mentioning are, by definition, unknowns.
Still, it is known they can and do happen. Likely "species" can
be identified that might lurk in any particular contract jungle
by tapping corporate memory (where it can be found) on both
first hand and second hand experience. From both disaster and
success in those experiences coping strategies can be developed
and worked into the contractual framework.
It is probably more difficult than polishing the documents
endlessly in search of perfection, it is messier and probably
gives less confidence as it admits there will be unknown
problems. It also probably works better than the false
confidence gained by presumed near perfection. It probably
significantly lessens "casualties."
By
Eric Ottinger on
Thursday, February 17, 2000 - 12:52 pm:
All,
It isn't that I disagree with Vern, but I find this somewhat
reminiscent of an old joke about academics to the effect that a
sociologist is a person who will spend $100,000 (probably a
million in current dollars) to find out something that he could
determine much more easily if he just asked.
Our friends in construction know all about bounded rationality.
Every time that we hand the contractor the perfect set of
blueprints, the contractor knows from long experience that he is
going to get well on changes.
We never learn from this experience. It is an article of faith
that the perfect blueprint (specification, SOW, etc.) is out
there in the ozone somewhere, and readily available if we could
just motivate our lazy experts to work harder.
Requirements change due to actions by third parties and higher
levels. My experience, (perhaps unique to my agency, but I doubt
it) is that all plans get perturbated and redirected frequently
with the redirection coming from numerous levels, up to and
including, Congress.
In this light, the perfect SOW requires both a comprehensive
listing of everything we know about the requirement today, and
20-20 foresight, several years into the future.
If we are honest and realistic, we will find a way to write our
service contracts with enough flexibility to accommodate such
additional direction and redirection without too much friction.
Eric
By
Gene Simmons on
Wednesday, February 16, 2000 - 04:48 pm:
Looking for a good sample of a
solicitation using PBSC for a FFP services/material contract.
Need a draft of QA and surveillance plan, deduction / incentive
schedule. Need asap for upcoming requirement
Thanks in advance for your time and assistance
By
Ramon on Wednesday, February 16, 2000 - 01:49 pm:
Excluding the bad faith aspects
of "cheat and lie" is there any interest in opening a thread
dealing with contractual and management mechanisms for dealing
with this very real world situation?
We don't want to get into what we'd like to do with cheaters and
liars, though various types of termination come to mind.
I expect Vern and others have some approaches that will help in
planning for the uncertain, building in coping mechanisms and
then managing the result.
By
Vern Edwards
on Wednesday, February 16, 2000 - 01:08 pm:
The Economic Institutions of
Capitalism: Firms, Markets, and Relational Contracting, by
Oliver E. Williamson (New York: The Free Press, 1985) is a very
good (but not easy) book that ties together the ideas of bounded
rationality, incomplete contracts, and transaction costs. The
book is available in paperback and you can generally find it in
the economics section of a Borders or Barnes and Nobles
bookstore. Of special interest to Open Forum readers are the
following chapters: 1. Transaction Cost Economics, 2.
Contractual Man, and 3. The Governance of Contractual Relations.
Here is a tantalizing and representative quote from Chapter 3,
page 70:
"Not every transaction fits comfortably into the classical
contracting scheme. In particular, for long-term contracts
executed under conditions of uncertainty complete presentiation
is apt to be prohibitively costly if not impossible. Problems of
several kinds arise. First, not all future contingencies for
which adaptations are required can be anticipated at the outset.
Second, the appropriate adaptations will not be evident for many
contingencies until the circumstances materialize. Third, except
as changes in states of the world are unambiguous, hard
contracting between autonomous parties may well give rise to
veridical disputes when state-contingent claims are made. In a
world where (at least some) parties are inclined to be
opportunistic, whose representations are to be believed?"
In plain English: Detailed, complete planning and specification
of required results for long-term contracts in environments
subject to frequent and/or rapid change are likely to be
impossible or excessively costly for the following reasons:
First, the contracting parties can't always identify all
requirements very far in advance. Second, even when they can
identify a contingent (might not happen) requirement, they can't
always decide in advance what the desired result (performance)
should be. Third, unless the facts are absolutely clear, if the
parties end up in conflict about their obligations one or both
may be inclined to cheat or lie.
This is a very good book, but as you can see it is not an easy
read. Even so, the effort will be worthwhile for those
professionals who want to develop a deeper understanding of the
nature and difficulties of service contracting.
By
Ramon on Wednesday, February 16, 2000 - 12:00 pm:
The web is a wonderful resource,
but no substitute for real libraries and books now as it tend to
be illustrative of that "mile wide and an inch deep" saying.
Still, a quick search gave a number of references for bounded
rationality. Not surprisingly, many are in the financial world
where such uncertainty abounds and exact science can't quite
reach.
A very basic definition is at
http://risk.ifci.ch/00010586.htm where the parent site is
devoted to risk in the financial world and might contain items
of interest to contracting people.
The first bullet of a slide at
http://www.cba.uh.edu/~jaana/class/c336907/sld009.htm struck
me as I was doing this quick search. I wonder how many times in
contract formulation that first available choice moving toward
the perceived goal has led down the path of disaster.
A more detailed paper, giving many citations that include other
works by Simon, is at
http://www.di.dk/di/fokus/laeringsprocesser/Towards_a_model.htm
where there is interesting discussion of individual knowledge
and leverage of group knowledge that might well apply in
contracting.
My feeling is that too much in contracting, where real money and
future performance by the Government itself is at stake, is
driven by politics, ego, rote, and expediency. In the old words,
"This ain't rocket science," but neither is it something where
scientific methods need be banned. I often thought it ironic
that the whole process leading up to contracting for and
demanding high performance in "engineering" was not itself
engineered.
Perhaps, even more than in engineering contracts, uncertainty
and the unexpected can arise in other types of services.
Experience should provide some foreknowledge of where those gray
areas may lie and mitigation strategies from R&D and engineering
could apply to routine maintenance and other "mundane"
contracts.
I have serious doubts about any effort to contract in "making
the customer happy" as that can change rapidly for short term
reasons having nothing to do with actual performance. I've seen
very unhappy customers come around to realize they got great
service and benefit and become "happy." I've also seen the
reverse and for no other reason than some external situation
changed mood. I do believe we can build in contractual
mechanisms that can prevent real that situation from being the
result of contractual inability to perform due to undefinable,
but not entirely unexpected, changes in the environment and
built in contractual constraints.
By
Michael Love on Wednesday, February 16, 2000 - 10:15 am:
Thanks for all the feedback.
This discussion is extremely helpful to me to help clarify my
thinking and hope to others. Here are some of my further
thoughts. I hope to get more of yours.
Looking at this from a purely contractual aspect, several points
emerge:
- Performance based service contracting should only be used
where appropriate. "Duh!" you say. But as I understand current
policy it is to be used in all (virtually) service contracts.
What is most often involved in long term, complex and frequently
changing relationships? People working together to best serve
other peoples' changing needs. In some cases I suspect that this
is nothing more than outsourced employees.
- Vern as usual you've added immeasurably to the discussion and
have made me schedule a trip to the library not knowing exactly
what "bounded rationality" is. But ignorance is no excuse for
silence.
- Complete planning is much more difficult if the task is to
describe how to do something or what to do in the future.
Describing end results once the service is delivered is easier,
for example neat well-trimmed lawns or a current, internet
connected desktop computer. So far that logic suggests
performance based contracting is the better and the even easier
way to go. Current thinking is the problems will disappear if
the contractor is told what the result should be, not how to get
there. This thinking is flawed in some significant respects. If
making the customer happy with whatever service the contractor
ultimately provides is specified, the contracting officer or the
CO's client who is responsible for the program has no good way
to manage it or, more precisely, to monitor contract performance
to ensure the end result is not disaster. Thus, particularly for
contracts of long duration, the real need is to specify some
intermediate performance measures at least. These can be
difficult to define contractually and most often become
directions on how to perform.
- Another point Vern and Ramon nailed is planning. There may be
some agencies that find it difficult to define what they have
received from a contractor, much less describe what they will
need. This is particularly difficult when the efforts of both
Government employees and contractors' employees have contributed
to the end results. How are these agencies to realistically do
anything but level of effort contracts? Only with difficulty and
through redefining some government employees' work.
- From a logical viewpoint, all of these issues can be addressed
but the question is whether current policies help or a hinder
doing so. Also whether these policies serve or hinder delivering
best value for tax dollars.
By Ramon on Tuesday, February
15, 2000 - 10:55 am:
A slightly different aspect of
the issue involves the inability to make any progress in the
pre-contract planning stage and subsequent funding emergency
with dying money. How many of us have been in contract
development sessions where everyone is wrapped around that axle?
I've seen, and I'm sure most others have seen, such meetings
bogged down and our own labor dollars going down the rathole of
trying to pin down some tiny detail that cannot be pinned down
at this stage. Then the issue gets pushed off to another session
or a study or a committee with no further progress. There are
cases where I'm sure ten times the amount of money was burned in
such sessions than on worst case event in the resulting
contract.
Parameters may have to be defined, but trying to define the
undefinable is a waste. It is much better to "cut bait" on that
effort and instead define how we can build in a defining
mechanism that allows us to work toward satisfactory solutions
within the contract.
By Ramon on Tuesday, February
15, 2000 - 10:33 am:
In my view part of the problem
Vern outlines so well is due to not planning for change with
frequent overconfidence that planning is already adequate. The
problem will not go away, but a contract predicated on
recognition of these facts, immediate planning for change and
structuring the contract itself to accomodate quick reaction to
those day-to-day surprises at the earliest stages of drafting
will help.
For example, a work statement that actually places an obligation
to accomodate the unexpected within certain parameters is a
possible method. It can even be backed by some funding that can
be used by mutual agreement to cover the unexpected while more
extensive adjustments are perhaps made for long term solution.
I think many of these problems come from trying to over plan,
over define, and being over confident that we have covered the
bases -- then we over constrain management. Early analysis and
recognition of the degrees of uncertainty, then planning for
mechanisms to accomodate them can go a long way in solving
problems. It applies to high tech, but also keeping bathrooms
clean during a snow emergency.
By Vern Edwards on Monday,
February 14, 2000 - 10:49 pm:
A correction to the fifth
paragraph of my previous post: technical direction clauses say
that technical direction does not include making changes.
I left out the word "not."
By
Vern Edwards
on Monday, February 14, 2000 - 04:53 pm:
Mike and Stan:
One reason that agency personnel want to engage in hands-on
supervision of contractor personnel is that contracts for
long-term, complex services are always incomplete. Better
planning can never solve the problem entirely because of bounded
rationality, a phenomenon that was first described by Herbert A.
Simon and which won him the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1978. He
describes the phenomenon in his book, Administrative Behavior,
4th ed. (New York: The Free Press, 1997), which is required
reading in virtually every college course in public
administration.
The problem of incomplete contracts has been analyzed in depth
by the University of California economist Oliver E. Williamson
and the University of Virginia law professor Ian R. MacNeil.
There is a large academic and business literature about this
problem. It comes up frequently in commercial publications such
as the Outsourcing Journal.
Performance-based service contracting (PBSC) policy requires
agency personnel to plan extensively, something that most of
them have not been trained to do; it also assumes that they can
plan completely, something that no one can do for complex
requirements. No matter how long and hard a group of people
think about the future, they will always leave something out. If
the future is dynamic and will be determined by forces and
events that cannot be controlled or anticipated, and if it is
complex, involving many, many "micro-requirements," which is
almost always the case, then then planning will be even more
inadequate.
PBSC policy does not recognize that parties in long-term,
complex relationships will have to engage in ad hoc, sequential
decision making, i.e., they will have to respond to requirements
as they emerge on an almost daily basis. It envisions static
contracts that we can award and then let the contractors perform
as they choose in order to achieve the required results. The
problem is that the required results are not static; they change
frequently.
That's why agency personnel want to supervise contractors. They
need to tell them what to do as new requirements emerge, which
happens daily in complex service functions. The change order
process is too cumbersome; NASA and DoD recognized this long ago
and developed "technical direction" clauses to cope with the
problem, but they tried to stay within the limits of
appropriations law, policy, and orthodoxy by claiming that
technical direction did include making changes to the statement
of work, a stance that is logically indefensible.
Long-term, complex service contracts are a relatively new
phenomenon in the world of business and government. They snuck
up on us during the late 70s and early 80s. We need to review
our service acquisition policies and bring them into line with
the realities of the present.
Vern
By
Stan Livingstone
on Monday, February 14, 2000 - 02:18 pm:
The current issue (February) of
the Nash & Cibinic Report has a timely and excellent article on
administering contracts with performance based SOWs. It's well
worth reading.
By
Stan Livingstone
on Monday, February 14, 2000 - 11:24 am:
From what I see, absolutely not.
I bet we can count on one hand the number of major contracts
fitting into the category you describe.
Writing a true performance based service SOW is hard enough.
Providing "hands off" administration makes it almost an
impossible task for program managers.
I hope my perception is wrong, but I haven't seen any instances
thus far and that's too bad.
By
Michael Love on Monday, February 14, 2000 - 10:11 am:
OMB is directing that agencies
use performance based service contracting, that is, tell the
contractor what goals to achieve, not how to achieve them.
Recently OMB also reported to Congress that most agencies were
doing a good job with this.
To do this effectively, IMHO, the contractor must be given
freedom to manage the contract effort. Something akin to a scope
of work that could be done for a fixed price. Note OMB guidance
for performance based service contracting specifies that it is
not limited to fixed price contracting.
But in order to give the government an ability to ensure
satisfactory performance, goals or metrics of some kind must be
available that indicate progress fairly frequently (at least
every 60 days?) otherwise months of effort can be wasted.
The GSA Seat management contracts are good examples of
performance-based systems with detailed metrics but no direction
on how the goals are to be achieved.
Now the point, I suspect that such performance based contracts
are still the exception. That most contracts are still a version
of personal services with performance based language in the
contract that is ignored during performance. Instead for
services that are more than lawn mowing or cleaning, the
government manages the work and the work force.
Recognizing that your responses will be anecdotal at best, I am
interested in your perception of whether agencies are really
delegating sufficient discretion to contractors on how to
perform that performance based service contracts are being
widely used.
|